GDP as a measure of economic well-being
Companies have developed new technologies for entertainment, travel, information, and health. A much wider variety of basic products like food and clothing is available today than several decades ago. GPI takes into account factors such as income distribution, environmental costs, and the value of household and volunteer work, aiming to measure sustainable economic welfare. The challenge is to account for non-market factors such as the value of leisure, health, and home production, such as cleaning, cooking and childcare, as well as the negative byproducts of economic activity, such as pollution and inequality. The fact that GDP per capita does not fully capture the broader idea of standard of living has led to a concern that the increases in GDP over time are illusory. It is theoretically possible that while GDP is rising, the standard of living could be falling if human health, environmental cleanliness, and other factors that are not included in GDP are worsening.
The authors did not receive financial support from any firm or person for this article or from any firm or person with a financial or political interest in this article. Neither is currently an officer, director, or board member of any organization with an interest in this article. While this new attention is welcome, economists and others who engage in this conversation do not always start on the same page. Conversations are impeded by a lack of understanding of how the statistics are defined and how they are limited, both in terms of the underlying concept and in terms of how they are calculated given the concept. Activities that result in benefits to others are called positive externalities.
- Conversations are impeded by a lack of understanding of how the statistics are defined and how they are limited, both in terms of the underlying concept and in terms of how they are calculated given the concept.
- Yet policymakers and economists often treat GDP, or GDP per capita in some cases, as an all-encompassing unit to signify a nation’s development, combining its economic prosperity and societal well-being.
- Our findings clearly suggest that per capita income or GDP does capture the main component of well-being.
- Introduction Briefly explain the role of GDP in economic measurement and its inadequacies in capturing welfare dimensions like inequality and environmental health.
Products and services
While it is not a comprehensive measure of welfare or even economic well-being, the GDP concept—along with the pieces of GDP available through the national accounts—is useful and provides a great deal of information about economic welfare. GDP is a measure of the final goods and services produced in an economy, those that are consumed by people or businesses. Intermediate goods and services are netted out in GDP because they are used to produce another good or service. The steel, plastic, and glass, for example, that are used to make it are intermediate products (or inputs). For example, non-monetary transactions like the services of the housewife are not included in the GDP.
6: How Well GDP Measures the Well-Being of Society
In a world where 1% of the population owns more than 50% of the wealth, perhaps we should be asking who benefits from economic activity – not simply how much economic activity there is. And while GDP fails to provide us with an accurate picture of economic activity, it fails even more in illustrating our true welfare. This is one of the main arguments in Pilling’s new book, the Growth Delusion. One problem is that the black market, cash-in-hand payments and tax evasion are all excluded from GDP calculations. A second issue is the number of non-monetised items produced in an economy. No single number can capture all the elements of a term as broad as “standard of living.” Nonetheless, GDP per capita is a reasonable, rough-and-ready measure of the standard of living.
A long-standing criticism of reliance explain the limitation of gdp as welfare. on GDP as the measure of economic success is that it excludes much unpaid work by households. There must be an accepted definition of what is part of the economy and measurable and what is not. Economists call this a “production boundary.” What is within that boundary and what is not inevitably involve matters of judgment.
Quality over Quantity: The Composition of GDP 🔗
We can present the welfare index for each quintile calculated from the components of life expectancy, consumption, leisure, and inequality, with US levels as a benchmark. As a group, the top fifth of countries based on income has a combined welfare index almost 7 percent below the US benchmark. The bottom fifth’s index is about 95 percent lower than that of the US. It is easier to express dissatisfaction with current measures than to reach consensus on what should replace GDP.
- However, this indicator has several blind spots that we need to shine a light on.
- There is no logical reason not to treat household work like any other work.
- When GDP per capita rises by 5%, it could mean that GDP for everyone in the society has risen by 5%, or that GDP of some groups has risen by more while that of others has risen by less—or even declined.
- And while GDP fails to provide us with an accurate picture of economic activity, it fails even more in illustrating our true welfare.
- GDP, as currently defined, should retain its stature as a major economic statistic.
Those who use GDP growth as a measure of economic performance must keep in mind that it has never been a complete measure of economic welfare. For example, the consumer benefits of an important new medicine will eventually always far exceed the market price. This argument, while correct, plays down the possibility of a particularly wide wedge between welfare and GDP today, given digital technology’s effects on business models and consumer behavior.
If a city is wrecked by a hurricane, and then experiences a surge of rebuilding construction activity, it would be peculiar to claim that the hurricane was therefore economically beneficial. If people are led by a rising fear of crime, to pay for installing bars and burglar alarms on all their windows, it is hard to believe that this increase in GDP has made them better off. Similarly, some people would argue that sales of certain goods, like pornography or extremely violent movies, do not represent a gain to society’s standard of living. Bad health also contributes to disruptions in employment, lowers productivity, and reduces economic growth.
However, as Raworth points out and was explored in the chapter on the labor market, even women who are fully employed expend significant effort (generally more than men) in raising children and maintaining a home. Raworth advocates that economic measures include monetized and un-monetized goods and services, so that the status and contributors to each economy are more accurate. GDP was not designed to assess welfare or the well being of citizens. Yet policymakers and economists often treat GDP as an all-encompassing unit to signify a nation’s development, combining its economic prosperity and societal well-being. It’s time to acknowledge the limitations of GDP and expand our view of development to include welfare. GDP’s shortcomings have become especially obvious recently in its failure to account for inequality.
While GDP includes what a country spends on environmental protection, healthcare, and education, it does not include actual levels of environmental cleanliness, health, and learning. GDP includes the cost of buying pollution-control equipment, but it does not address whether the air and water are actually cleaner or dirtier. GDP includes spending on medical care, but does not address whether life expectancy or infant mortality have risen or fallen. Similarly, it counts spending on education, but does not address directly how much of the population can read, write, or do basic mathematics. When we talk about a country’s economic health, Gross Domestic Product (GDP) often takes center stage in the conversation. But have you ever stopped to wonder if GDP truly captures the essence of economic welfare?
When income distribution did not change much—until the mid-1980s in most OECD countries—ignoring the issue did not matter much. However, thanks in part to Thomas Piketty’s bestselling Capital in the Twenty-First Century and in part to the populist movements springing up in many countries, nobody is ignoring distributional questions anymore. If the price of shoes, say, is 5 percent higher than a year ago and GDP registers a 5 percent increase in the value of shoe output, the nominal increase in the shoe component of GDP is an illusion, due to inflation. To determine how much of any, say, year-to-year change in GDP reflects more final output (volume) and how much reflects higher prices (inflation), economists use a technique called deflation.